Governing
the European Union, by Michele Boselli
5. To what
extent does the evidence support the view that the European Union is
creating a single economy for its member states?
Nowadays it
would seem pretty easy to say that the European Union is creating a
single economy for its member states: it is a view supported to a
great extent by the Evidence of the Euro, the single currency
recently introduced among 12 of the 15 countries (the exceptions
being Denmark, Sweden and the UK). A currency is only an (important)
element of the economy, which is made up of complex relations of many
other elements, such as social framework, macroeconomic institutions,
political intervention, corporate governance…, and the question
should be addressed with a historical view to the developments that
through the last five decades led to this great conquest towards
integration.
The most
evident data is the growth of intra-EU trade from 35.2% in 1958 to
62.6 in 1993, just 35 years. This is resulting from the gradual but
continuous integration among the European national economies, an
objective pursued above all by the successful establishment of a
common market founded on the four freedoms of the Treaty of Rome
(freedom of trade, investment, labour movement and service
provision), and also pursuing common, albeit controversial policies
in important issues such as agriculture and VAT harmonisation. This
is the exten to to which we can seriously talk of an European
economy, on the verge of the monetary union, but many differences
persist and we now aim to see where.
In order to
address this question we cannot examine every single economy of the
15 member states and the other 15 or more of the continent. We must
necessarily simplify by examining three countries that best represent
the three main economic systems in Europe: the United Kingdom, with
an Anglo-American, market-oriented system; Germany, with a
regulatory-oriented system similar to other important European
countries such as Sweden; and France, with a slightly different
“Mediterranean” version of the regulatory-oriented system, closer
to that of the fourth big European economy, Italy.
By taking
such approach we imply a more basic distinction between
Anglo-American and continental economies which reflects two different
systems: the market-oriented order is characterised by more
competition and it is self-regulated by the invisible guiding hand of
the market itself; banks play a minor role, and the stock exchange a
major one, in companies’ ownership, which is a separate thing from
management; most important from the social point of view, the
influence of employees is very limited in the decision-making
process, which is rather the outcome of how the market “awards”
the merits of a (highly incentivated) management or punishes it by
means of deregulated, hostile take-overs from winning companies. To
summarize this in ome single word related to a very important,
recurrent concept in our studies, Grahame Thompson simply writes
“non-governance” in Governing the European economy.
On the other
hand, in the regulatory order there is a state bureaucracy
supervising the economy, a nuch more significant participation of
banks at the expenses of relatively smaller stock exchanges, and
extensive control by families traditionally owning the companies (in
particukar small and medium-sized enterprises that make up the
economic tissue of many European regions). There is, in sum, an
active intervention in the governance of the economy, which comprises
a stronger influence by workers, organised in large trade unions, and
also by an articulated system of cross-participation: for example in
chapter 3 of the same Governing the European economy, Michael
Moran shows that the Deutsche Bank owns 7% of the insurance
group Allianz which in turn owns 5% of Deutsche Bank,
and the same happens between Allianz and Dresdner Bank
(owning respectively 21.7% and 10% of each other), so that we can
paradoxically extrapolate that through Allianz both Deutsche
and Dresdner banks own part of each other (respectively 0.5%
and 1.5%), and consequently even that even through this web of
participation car maker Daimler becomes a remote "cousin"
of its fiercest domestic competitor, BMW, and vice versa.
Hoping that
this gross, inevitably summary in its conciseness, representation of
the two systems is clear (we will not tackle the subtler subdivision
within the regulatory order, i.e. the Germanic and Mediterranean
varieties), we now learn from Graham Watson (Governing the
European economy, chapter 4) that "the German macroeconomic
policy framework was more influential on the design of the EU
macroeconomic policy and institutions than those of the UK and
France". This means that the governance of the economy has had a
heavy de jure, "positive" intervention besides the
"negative" de facto intervention: polarities that
characterise the regulatory and the market order respectively.
Critics of
this vision (or indeed of the regulatory system itself) point out
that in the 1970s and 1980s there has been a move from the regulatory
order towards a market order among the EU economies. this will become
an increasing necessity as greater problems will loom in the next
round of enlargements towards Central and Eastern European countries:
for example, a regulatory policy par excellence such as the
Common Agricultural Policy like we know it today will be
unsustainable in an Union comprising Poland. They highlight that the
crisis of the European social model of the 1950s and 1960s led to a
reform in the need of greater flexibility in the labour market and
welfare provision. The balance point in this debate would probably
be, as Dawson concludes, that "the experience of economic and
monetary union so far suggests that the EU macroeconomic polici is
based on a pragmatic blending of Keynesian and neo-liberal elements",
where Keynesian refers to the economist's theories, particularly on
unemployment.
Thw Union, in
fact, has so far produced little in terms of a common social policy,
which is an essential element of integration. Back to the Euro, for
example, the Maastricht convergence criteria for the single currency
are merely monetary, including inflation, interest rates and
government finances but exluding unemployment. This brings us again
to simplify the social aspects by taking the same three big countries
to represent the major tendencies. Social policy is the field where
Germany and France broadly agree on stricter worker protection laws,
a greater consultation with trade unions, and a consumer protection
to ensure transparency about the origin of products. The UK is
fiercely protective on social security questions and won the right to
keep its veto on the matter.
On taxation
policies, Europe already has a degree of tax harmonisation - for
example VAT rates are set with a certain minimum in order to make the
single market more effective. The three big member states have
different views on whether there should be further harmonisation, but
now maintains that taxation policies should remain at national or
regional government level. France supports the view of the European
Commission that a new, direct tax should be levied by Brussels to
provide a direct link between citizens and the EU, and wants a
unified tax policy, including common rules for business taxes, but
the UK is strongly opposed to a common tax policy and refuses to give
up its veto on tax decisions.
In
conclusion, the debate on the European economies' degree of
integration has again taken us to the usual themes of our studies:
tradition and transformation (the evolution of the economies);
conflict and consensus (the social issues); inclusion and exclusion
(of employees in the decision-making process, or even whole countries
in the Union). There is a theme that revealed itself to be more
important in the case in study, in the sense that both supporters of
the regulatory and the market approach would probably agree on it as
a picture of the situation, rather than take sides on the
positive/negative polarities (centralisation/decentralisation, de
jure / de facto, ...) that we have examines, and it is that of
unity and diversity.
The EU member
states' economies were very different in the post Second World War
period, when "a real tendency for a single European social model
(or family of models), involving similar industrial relations systems
and social protection systems" emerged (John Grahl, Governing
the European economy, chapter 5) and these economies have since
then converged toward a common position in many areas. They still
differ in their approaches to the welfare state, employment law and
trade union organisation, divided into two broad types: the
Anglo-American version and the continental European version. These
differences are important in limiting integration because there is an
issue - Grahl concludes - about the long-term prospects for
successful economic integration among economies with disparate
unemployment rates. That will be the next, very difficult challenge
towards a European single economy, while the common market and the
monetary union remain, nonetheless, historical achievements.
Nessun commento:
Posta un commento